List of Nobel Memorial Prize laureates in Economic Sciences facts for kids

The Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences is a very important award for people who study economics. It's officially called "The Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel." This prize is paid for by Sveriges Riksbank, which is Sweden's central bank. Each year, the Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences gives this award to researchers who have made big discoveries in economics.
The first prize was given out in 1969 to Ragnar Frisch and Jan Tinbergen. Winners receive a special medal, a diploma, and money. For example, in 1969, Frisch and Tinbergen shared 375,000 Swedish Krona (SEK). This amount changes over the years. The award ceremony happens in Stockholm every year on December 10th. This date is important because it's the day Alfred Nobel passed away.
Up to 2023, 55 prizes have been given to 93 different people. The University of Chicago has had the most winners in economics, with 16 people linked to it. Also, Harvard University and MIT have had the most students who earned their PhDs there and later won the prize (13 each). The University of Chicago is close behind with 10. Many winners were also teaching at the University of Chicago when they received the award (15 winners). MIT, Princeton University, and Harvard University each had 8 winners teaching there at the time.
Winners of the Economics Prize
Contents
|
Year | Picture | Winner (birth/death) |
Country | Why they won | University where they got their PhD | Main university they worked at | Key ideas (some examples) |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
1969 | ![]() |
Ragnar Frisch (1895–1973) |
![]() |
"for creating and using models to understand how economies change over time." | University of Oslo | University of Oslo | Frisch–Waugh–Lovell theorem, Conjectural variation |
![]() |
Jan Tinbergen (1903–1994) |
![]() |
Leiden University | Erasmus University | Econometrics (using math in economics), Economic policy tools | ||
1970 | ![]() |
Paul Samuelson (1915–2009) |
![]() |
"for his work that helped develop economic theory and made economic analysis better." | Harvard University | Massachusetts Institute of Technology | Revealed preference (how choices show preferences), Samuelson condition, Social Welfare Function |
1971 | ![]() |
Simon Kuznets (1901–1985) |
![]() |
"for explaining economic growth based on facts. This helped us understand how economies and societies develop." | Columbia University | Harvard University | Gross domestic product (GDP), Capital formation, Kuznets curve |
1972 | ![]() |
John Hicks (1904–1989) |
![]() |
"for their early work on how all parts of an economy balance out, and on welfare economics." | University of Oxford | University of Oxford | IS–LM model, Hicksian demand function |
![]() |
Kenneth Arrow (1921–2017) |
![]() |
Columbia University | Harvard University | Fundamental theorems of welfare economics, Arrow's impossibility theorem | ||
1973 | ![]() |
Wassily Leontief (1905–1999) |
![]() ![]() |
"for creating the input-output method and using it to solve important economic problems." | University of Berlin | Harvard University | Input–output model, Leontief paradox |
1974 | ![]() |
Gunnar Myrdal (1898–1987) |
![]() |
"for their early work on money and economic ups and downs. They also looked at how economic, social, and other factors are connected." | Stockholm University | Stockholm University | Circular cumulative causation |
![]() |
Friedrich Hayek (1899–1992) |
![]() ![]() |
University of Vienna | Austrian business cycle theory, Economic calculation problem | |||
1975 | ![]() |
Leonid Kantorovich (1912–1986) |
![]() |
"for their ideas on how to best use resources." | Leningrad State University | Novosibirsk State University | Linear programming |
![]() |
Tjalling Koopmans (1910–1985) |
![]() ![]() |
University of Leiden | Linear programming | |||
1976 | ![]() |
Milton Friedman (1912–2006) |
![]() |
"for his work on how people spend money, the history and theory of money, and showing how hard it is to keep the economy stable." | Columbia University | University of Chicago | Monetarism, Permanent income hypothesis |
1977 | ![]() |
Bertil Ohlin (1899–1979) |
![]() |
"for their important work on international trade and how money moves between countries." | Stockholm University | Stockholm School of Economics | Heckscher–Ohlin model |
![]() |
James Meade (1907–1995) |
![]() |
University of Cambridge | University of Cambridge | Nominal income target | ||
1978 | ![]() |
Herbert A. Simon (1916–2001) |
![]() |
"for his early research into how people make decisions inside economic groups." | University of Chicago | Carnegie Mellon University | Bounded rationality, satisficing |
1979 | ![]() |
Theodore Schultz (1902–1998) |
![]() |
"for their early research into economic development, especially for developing countries." | University of Wisconsin-Madison | University of Chicago | Human Capital Theory |
Arthur Lewis (1915–1991) |
![]() ![]() |
London School of Economics | Princeton University | Lewis model | |||
1980 | ![]() |
Lawrence Klein (1920–2013) |
![]() |
"for creating models that use math to predict economic changes and understand economic policies." | Massachusetts Institute of Technology | University of Pennsylvania | Economic forecasting |
1981 | ![]() |
James Tobin (1918–2002) |
![]() |
"for his study of financial markets and how they relate to spending, jobs, production, and prices." | Harvard University | Yale University | Tobin tax, Tobin's q |
1982 | George Stigler (1911–1991) |
![]() |
"for his important studies of how industries are set up, how markets work, and why and how public rules affect them." | University of Chicago | University of Chicago | Regulatory capture | |
1983 | ![]() |
Gérard Debreu (1921–2004) |
![]() |
"for bringing new math methods into economic theory and clearly explaining the theory of general equilibrium." | University of Paris | University of California, Berkeley | Arrow–Debreu model |
1984 | Richard Stone (1913–1991) |
![]() |
"for his key work in creating systems for national accounts. This greatly improved how we analyze economic data." | University of Cambridge | University of Cambridge | National accounts | |
1985 | ![]() |
Franco Modigliani (1918–2003) |
![]() |
"for his early studies of saving and financial markets." | The New School for Social Research | Massachusetts Institute of Technology | Modigliani–Miller theorem, Life-cycle hypothesis |
1986 | ![]() |
James M. Buchanan (1919–2013) |
![]() |
"for developing the ideas of contracts and rules that form the basis of how economic and political decisions are made." | University of Chicago | George Mason University | Constitutional economics |
1987 | ![]() |
Robert Solow (1924–2023) |
![]() |
"for his ideas on how economies grow." | Harvard University | Massachusetts Institute of Technology | Solow–Swan model |
1988 | ![]() |
Maurice Allais (1911–2010) |
![]() |
"for his early work on how markets work and how to use resources well." | École Polytechnique |
|
OLG model, Allais paradox |
1989 | ![]() |
Trygve Haavelmo (1911–1999) |
![]() |
"for making clear the math foundations of econometrics and his studies of how different parts of the economy work together." | University of Oslo | University of Oslo | Balanced budget multiplier |
1990 | Harry Markowitz (1927–2023) |
![]() |
"for their early work in the theory of financial economics." | University of Chicago | City University of New York | Modern portfolio theory | |
Merton Miller (1923–2000) |
Johns Hopkins University | Modigliani–Miller theorem | |||||
![]() |
William F. Sharpe (b. 1934) |
University of California, Los Angeles | Stanford University | Sharpe Ratio | |||
1991 | ![]() |
Ronald Coase (1910–2013) |
![]() |
"for finding and explaining the importance of transaction costs and property rights for how the economy is set up and how it works." | London School of Economics | Transaction costs, Coase theorem | |
1992 | ![]() |
Gary Becker (1930–2014) |
![]() |
"for expanding the study of economics to many areas of human behaviour and how people interact, even outside of markets." | University of Chicago | University of Chicago | Human Capital Theory |
1993 | ![]() |
Robert Fogel (1926–2013) |
![]() |
"for making new research in economic history by using economic ideas and math to explain how economies and rules change." | Johns Hopkins University | University of Chicago | Cliometrics |
![]() |
Douglass North (1920–2015) |
University of California, Berkeley | Washington University in St. Louis | ||||
1994 | John Harsanyi (1920–2000) |
![]() ![]() |
"for their early study of balanced situations in non-cooperative games." | Stanford University | University of California, Berkeley | Bayesian game | |
![]() |
John Forbes Nash (1928–2015) |
![]() |
Princeton University | Princeton University | Nash equilibrium | ||
![]() |
Reinhard Selten (1930–2016) |
![]() |
Goethe University Frankfurt | University of Bonn | Experimental economics | ||
1995 | ![]() |
Robert Lucas, Jr. (1937–2023) |
![]() |
"for developing and using the idea of rational expectations. This changed macroeconomic analysis and helped us understand economic policy better." | University of Chicago | University of Chicago | Rational expectations, Lucas critique |
1996 | ![]() |
James Mirrlees (1936–2018) |
![]() |
"for their important ideas in economics about how people are motivated when they don't have all the information." | University of Cambridge | Optimal labor income taxation | |
William Vickrey (1914–1996) |
![]() ![]() |
Columbia University | Columbia University | Vickrey auction | |||
1997 | ![]() |
Robert C. Merton (b. 1944) |
![]() |
"for a new way to figure out the value of financial derivatives." | Massachusetts Institute of Technology | Massachusetts Institute of Technology | Black–Scholes–Merton model |
![]() |
Myron Scholes (b. 1941) |
![]() ![]() |
University of Chicago | Stanford University | Black–Scholes–Merton model | ||
1998 | ![]() |
Amartya Sen (b. 1933) |
![]() |
"for his contributions to welfare economics" (how to make society better off). | University of Cambridge | Human development theory | |
1999 | ![]() |
Robert Mundell (1932–2021) |
![]() |
"for his study of money and fiscal policy under different exchange rate systems, and his ideas on best currency areas." | Massachusetts Institute of Technology | Columbia University | Optimum currency area, Mundell–Fleming model |
2000 | ![]() |
James Heckman (b. 1944) |
![]() |
"for creating theories and methods to analyze specific groups of data." | Princeton University | University of Chicago | Heckman correction |
Daniel McFadden (b. 1937) |
"for creating theories and methods to analyze discrete choice (when people choose from a few options)." | University of Minnesota | Discrete choice models | ||||
2001 | ![]() |
George Akerlof (b. 1940) |
![]() |
"for their studies of markets where some people have more information than others." | Massachusetts Institute of Technology | Adverse selection (The Market for Lemons) | |
![]() |
Michael Spence (b. 1943) |
Harvard University | Harvard University | Signalling theory | |||
![]() |
Joseph Stiglitz (b. 1943) |
Massachusetts Institute of Technology | Screening theory | ||||
2002 | ![]() |
Daniel Kahneman (1934–2024) |
![]() ![]() |
"for bringing ideas from psychology into economics, especially about how people judge and make decisions when things are uncertain." | University of California, Berkeley | Behavioral economics, Prospect theory | |
![]() |
Vernon L. Smith (b. 1927) |
![]() |
"for making laboratory experiments a way to study economics, especially for looking at different market systems." | Harvard University | University of Arizona | Experimental economics | |
2003 | ![]() |
Robert F. Engle (b. 1942) |
![]() |
"for methods to analyze economic data that changes how much it varies over time." | Cornell University | University of California, San Diego | ARCH |
![]() |
Clive Granger (1934–2009) |
![]() |
"for methods to analyze economic data that move together over time." | University of Nottingham | University of California, San Diego | Cointegration, Granger causality | |
2004 | ![]() |
Finn E. Kydland (b. 1943) |
![]() |
"for their ideas on how economic policies change over time and what causes business cycles (economic ups and downs)." | Carnegie Mellon University | University of California, Santa Barbara | RBC theory |
![]() |
Edward C. Prescott (1940–2022) |
![]() |
Carnegie Mellon University | Hodrick-Prescott filter | |||
2005 | ![]() |
Robert J. Aumann (b. 1930) |
![]() ![]() |
"for helping us understand conflict and cooperation using game theory." | Massachusetts Institute of Technology | Hebrew University of Jerusalem | Correlated equilibrium |
![]() |
Thomas C. Schelling (1921–2016) |
![]() |
Harvard University | Schelling point | |||
2006 | ![]() |
Edmund S. Phelps (b. 1933) |
![]() |
"for his study of how choices today affect the future in macroeconomic policy." | Yale University | Columbia University | Golden Rule savings rate, Natural rate of unemployment |
2007 | ![]() |
Leonid Hurwicz (1917–2008) |
![]() ![]() |
"for creating the basic ideas of mechanism design theory." | London School of Economics | Mechanism design | |
![]() |
Eric S. Maskin (b. 1950) |
![]() |
Harvard University | Harvard University | |||
![]() |
Roger Myerson (b. 1951) |
Harvard University | Northwestern University | ||||
2008 | ![]() |
Paul Krugman (b. 1953) |
![]() |
"for his study of trade patterns and where economic activities happen." | Massachusetts Institute of Technology | Princeton University | New trade theory, New Economic Geography |
2009 | ![]() |
Elinor Ostrom (1933–2012) |
![]() |
"for her study of how economic groups are managed, especially for shared resources." | University of California, Los Angeles | Indiana University | Institutional Analysis and Development framework |
![]() |
Oliver E. Williamson (1932–2020) |
"for his study of how economic groups are managed, especially the limits of a company." | Carnegie Mellon University | New institutional economics | |||
2010 | ![]() |
Peter A. Diamond (b. 1940) |
![]() |
"for their study of markets where buyers and sellers need to find each other." | Massachusetts Institute of Technology | Massachusetts Institute of Technology | Diamond–Mirrlees efficiency theorem |
![]() |
Dale T. Mortensen (1939–2014) |
Carnegie Mellon University | Northwestern University | Matching theory | |||
![]() |
Christopher A. Pissarides (b. 1948) |
![]() ![]() |
London School of Economics | London School of Economics | Matching theory | ||
2011 | ![]() |
Thomas J. Sargent (b. 1943) |
![]() |
"for their research on cause and effect in the overall economy." | Harvard University |
|
Policy-ineffectiveness proposition |
![]() |
Christopher A. Sims (b. 1942) |
Harvard University | Princeton University | Vector autoregression in macroeconomics | |||
2012 | ![]() |
Alvin E. Roth (b. 1951) |
![]() |
"for the theory of stable matches and how to design markets." | Stanford University | Stable marriage problem | |
![]() |
Lloyd S. Shapley (1923–2016) |
Princeton University | University of California, Los Angeles | Shapley value, Gale–Shapley algorithm | |||
2013 | ![]() |
Eugene F. Fama (b. 1939) |
![]() |
"for their research on how asset prices behave." | University of Chicago | University of Chicago | Fama–French three-factor model, efficient-market hypothesis |
![]() |
Lars Peter Hansen (b. 1952) |
University of Minnesota | University of Chicago | Generalized method of moments | |||
![]() |
Robert J. Shiller (b. 1946) |
Massachusetts Institute of Technology | Yale University | Case–Shiller index | |||
2014 | ![]() |
Jean Tirole (b. 1953) |
![]() |
"for his study of market power and how to regulate it." | Massachusetts Institute of Technology | Markov perfect equilibrium, Two-sided market | |
2015 | ![]() |
Angus Deaton (b. 1945) |
![]() ![]() |
"for his study of how people consume, poverty, and well-being." | University of Cambridge | Princeton University | Almost ideal demand system, Household surveys |
2016 | ![]() |
Oliver Hart (b. 1948) |
![]() ![]() |
"for their important ideas about contract theory." | Princeton University | Harvard University | Moral Hazard, Incomplete contracts |
Bengt Holmström (b. 1949) |
![]() |
Stanford University | Massachusetts Institute of Technology | Informativeness Principle | |||
2017 | ![]() |
Richard Thaler (b. 1945) |
![]() |
"for his ideas in behavioural economics" (how psychology affects economic decisions). | University of Rochester | Nudge Theory, Mental Accounting | |
2018 | ![]() |
William Nordhaus (b. 1941) |
![]() |
"for adding climate change into long-term economic analysis." | Massachusetts Institute of Technology | Yale University | DICE model |
![]() |
Paul Romer (b. 1955) |
"for adding new technology ideas into long-term economic analysis." | University of Chicago | New York University | Incorporation of R&D to the Endogenous growth theory | ||
2019 | ![]() |
Abhijit Banerjee (b. 1961) |
![]() |
"for their experimental way of helping reduce global poverty." | Harvard University | Massachusetts Institute of Technology | Use of RCTs in development economics |
![]() |
Esther Duflo (b. 1972) |
![]() ![]() |
Massachusetts Institute of Technology | Massachusetts Institute of Technology | |||
![]() |
Michael Kremer (b. 1964) |
![]() |
Harvard University | Harvard University | |||
2020 | ![]() |
Paul Milgrom (b. 1948) |
![]() |
"for making auction theory better and inventing new ways to run auctions." | Stanford University | Stanford University | Simultaneous multiple round auctions (SMRA), Market design |
Robert B. Wilson (b. 1937) |
Harvard University | Stanford University | Simultaneous multiple round auctions (SMRA), Common value auction | ||||
2021 | ![]() |
David Card (b. 1956) |
![]() ![]() |
"for his research on jobs and the economy." | Princeton University | University of California, Berkeley | Natural experiments on labor economics |
![]() |
Joshua Angrist (b. 1960) |
![]() ![]() |
"for their methods to figure out cause and effect in economics." | Princeton University | Massachusetts Institute of Technology | Using natural experiments to find cause and effect | |
![]() |
Guido Imbens (b. 1963) |
![]() ![]() |
Brown University | Stanford University | |||
2022 | ![]() |
Ben Bernanke (b. 1953) |
![]() |
"for research on banks and financial crises." | Massachusetts Institute of Technology | Analysis of the Great Depression | |
![]() |
Douglas Diamond (b. 1953) |
Yale University | University of Chicago | Diamond–Dybvig model | |||
![]() |
Philip H. Dybvig (b. 1955) |
Yale University | Washington University in St. Louis | ||||
2023 | ![]() |
Claudia Goldin (b. 1946) |
![]() |
"for helping us understand women's roles in the job market." | University of Chicago | Harvard University | Study of women's economic history |
2024 | ![]() |
Daron Acemoglu (b. 1967) |
![]() ![]() |
"for studies of how institutions (rules and organizations) are formed and affect how rich a country becomes." | London School of Economics | ||
Simon Johnson (b. 1963) |
![]() ![]() |
Massachusetts Institute of Technology | Massachusetts Institute of Technology | ||||
![]() |
James A. Robinson (b. 1955) |
![]() |
Yale University | University of Chicago |
Universities Where Winners Got Their PhDs
This table shows which universities have produced the most Nobel Prize winners in economics.
Winners by Country
This table shows how many Nobel Prize winners in economics come from each country.
Country | Number of winners |
---|---|
![]() |
70 |
![]() |
13 |
![]() |
4 |
![]() |
4 |
![]() |
3 |
![]() |
3 |
![]() |
3 |
![]() |
2 |
![]() |
2 |
![]() |
2 |
![]() |
1 |
![]() |
1 |
![]() |
1 |
![]() |
1 |
![]() |
1 |
![]() |
1 |
![]() |
1 |
![]() |
1 |
![]() |
1 |